1
Inflation targeting is a monetary policy strategy that encompasses five main elements: 1)
the public announcement of medium-term numerical targets for inflation; 2) an institutional
commitment to price stability as the primary goal of monetary policy, to which other goals are
subordinated; 3) an information inclusive strategy in which many variables, and not just monetary
aggregates or the exchange rate, are used for deciding the setting of policy instruments; 4)
increased transparency of the monetary policy strategy through communication with the public and
the markets about the plans, objectives, and decisions of the monetary authorities; and 5) increased.2
accountability of the central bank for attaining its inflation objectives. The list should clarify one
crucial point about inflation targeting: it entails much more than a public announcement of
numerical targets for inflation for the year ahead. This is important in the context of emerging
markets’ countries because many of them routinely reported numerical inflation targets or
objectives as part of the government's economic plan for the coming year, and yet their monetary
policy strategy should not be characterized as inflation targeting, which requires the other four
elements for it to be sustainable over the medium term.
Inflation targeting has several advantages as a medium-term strategy for monetary
policy. In contrast to an exchange rate peg, inflation targeting enables monetary policy to focus
on domestic considerations and to respond to shocks to the domestic economy. In contrast to
monetary targeting, another possible monetary policy strategy, inflation targeting has the
advantage that a stable relationship between money and inflation is not critical to its success:
the strategy does not depend on such a relationship, but instead uses all available information
to determine the best settings for the instruments of monetary policy. Inflation targeting also
has the key advantage that it is easily understood by the public and is thus highly transparent.
Because an explicit numerical target for inflation increases the accountability of the
central bank, inflation targeting also has the potential to reduce the likelihood that the central
bank will fall into the time-inconsistency trap. Moreover, since the source of time-inconsistency
is often found in (covert or open) political pressures on the central bank to
undertake overly expansionary monetary policy, inflation targeting has the advantage of.3
focusing the political debate on what a central bank can do in the long-run -- i.e., control
inflation -- rather than what it cannot do -- raise output growth, lower unemployment, increase
external competitiveness-- through monetary policy. For inflation targeting to deliver these
outcomes, there must exist a strong institutional commitment to make price stability the primary
goal of the central bank. This is particularly important in emerging market countries which
have often had a past history of monetary mismanagement. The institutional commitment
involves legislative support for an independent central bank whose charter ought to contain two
key features: 1) sufficient insulation of the policymaking board of the central bank from the
politicians--with members of the government excluded and the members of the board appointed
to long terms and protected from arbitrary dismissal; and 2) giving the central bank full and
exclusive control over the setting of monetary policy instruments. The institutional commitment
to price stability also requires that the central bank be given a mandate to have price stability
as its primary goal, making it clear that when there is a conflict with other goals, such as
exchange rate stability or promotion of high employment, price stability must be accorded the
higher priority.
Inflation-targeting regimes also put great stress on the need to make monetary policy
transparent and to maintain regular channels of communication with the public; in fact, these
features have been central to the strategy's success in industrialized countries. As illustrated in
Frederic Mishkin and Adam Posen (1997), and in Ben Bernanke, Thomas Laubach, Frederic
Mishkin and Adam Posen (1999), inflation-targeting central banks have frequent
communications with the government, and their officials take every opportunity to make public
speeches on their monetary policy strategy. Inflation targeting central banks have taken public
outreach a step further: they publish Inflation Report-type documents (originated by the Bank.4
of England) to clearly present their views about the past and future performance of inflation and
monetary policy.
Another key feature of inflation-targeting regimes is that the transparency of policy
associated with inflation targeting has tended to make the central bank highly accountable to
the public. Sustained success in the conduct of monetary policy as measured against a pre-announced
and well-defined inflation target can be instrumental in building public support for
an independent central bank, even in the absence of a rigidly defined and legalistic standard of
performance evaluation and punishment.
Critics of inflation targeting have noted seven major disadvantages of this monetary
policy strategy. Four of those disadvantages -- that inflation targeting is too rigid, that it allows
too much discretion, that it has the potential to increase output instability, and that it will lower
economic growth-- have been discussed in Mishkin (1999) and in Bernanke, et al. (1999), and
are in reality not serious objections to a properly designed inflation targeting strategy which is
best characterized as “constrained discretion”. The fifth disadvantage, that inflation targeting
can only produce weak central bank accountability because inflation is hard to control and
because there are long lags from the monetary policy instruments to the inflation outcome, is
an especially serious one for emerging market countries. The sixth and seventh disadvantages,
that inflation targeting cannot prevent fiscal dominance, and that the exchange rate flexibility
required by inflation targeting might cause financial instability, are also very relevant in the
emerging market country context..5
In contrast to exchange rates and monetary aggregates, the inflation rate cannot be easily controlled by the central bank; furthermore, inflation outcomes that incorporate the effects of changes in instruments settings are revealed only after a substantial lag. The difficulty of controlling inflation creates a particularly severe problem for emerging market countries when inflation is being brought down from relatively high levels. In those circumstances, inflation forecast errors are likely to be large, inflation targets will tend to be missed, and it will be difficult for the central bank to gain credibility from an inflation targeting strategy, and for the public to ascertain the reasons for the deviations. This suggests that, as noted by Paul Masson, Miguel Savastano and Sunil Sharma (1997), inflation targeting is likely to be a more effective strategy if it is phased in only after there has been some successful disinflation.
One other factor affecting inflation controllability that is especially relevant in the emerging market context is the (at times large) incidence of government-controlled prices on the index used to compute headline inflation. As a result inflation targeting may demand a high degree of coordination between monetary and fiscal authorities on the timing and magnitude of future changes in controlled prices or, alternatively, the exclusion of controlled prices from the targeted price index, as in the Czech Republic.
A sixth shortcoming of inflation targeting is that it may not be sufficient to ensure fiscal
discipline or prevent fiscal dominance. Governments can still pursue irresponsible fiscal policy
with an inflation targeting regime in place. In the long run, large fiscal deficits will cause an
inflation targeting regime to break down: the fiscal deficits will eventually have to be
monetized or the public debt eroded by a large devaluation, and high inflation will follow.
Absence of outright fiscal dominance is therefore a key prerequisite for inflation targeting, and
the setting up of institutions that help keep fiscal policy in check are crucial to the success of.6
the strategy (Masson et al., 1997) Similarly, a sound financial system is another prerequisite
for successful inflation targeting because when financial systems blow up, there is typically a
surge in inflation in emerging market countries. However, as pointed out in Frederic Mishkin
and Miguel Savastano (1999), a sound financial system and the absence of fiscal dominance
are also crucial to the sustainability and success of any other monetary policy strategy,
including a currency board or full dollarization. Indeed, inflation targeting may help constrain
fiscal policy to the extent that the government is actively involved in setting the inflation target
(including through the coordination of future adjustments to government-controlled prices).
Finally, a high degree of (partial) dollarization may create a potentially serious problem
for inflation targeting. In fact, in many emerging market countries the balance sheets of firms,
households and banks are substantially dollarized, on both sides, and the bulk of long-term
debt is denominated in dollars (Guillermo Calvo, 1999). Because inflation targeting necessarily
requires nominal exchange rate flexibility, exchange rate fluctuations are unavoidable.
However, large and abrupt depreciations may increase the burden of dollar-denominated debt,
produce a massive deterioration of balance sheets, and increase the risks of a financial crisis
along the lines discussed in Mishkin (1996). This suggests that emerging market countries
cannot afford to ignore the exchange rate when conducting monetary policy under inflation
targeting, but the role they ascribe to is should be clearly subordinated to the inflation objective.
It also suggests that inflation targeting in partially dollarized economies may not be viable
unless there are stringent prudential regulations on, and strict supervision of, financial
institutions that ensure that the system is capable of withstanding exchange rate shocks.
The earliest example of an emerging market country adopting inflation targeting is Chile,
which in 1990, with the inflation rate in excess of 20%, first started to announce an inflation
objective in September for the twelve-month inflation rate ending in December of the following
year.1 As pointed out above, for inflation targeting to be a success, institutions in the country must
support independence of the central bank, as well as a strong fiscal position and sound financial
system. Before embarking on inflation targeting, Chile passed new central bank legislation in
11989 (that took effect in 1990), which gave independence to the central bank and mandated price
stability as one of its primary objectives.2 A sound fiscal policy was also in place, with the fiscal
balance in surplus in every year from 1991 to 1997. In addition, due largely to the measures taken
in the aftermath of its severe banking crisis in the early 1980s, Chile’s standards and practices in
the areas of banking regulation and supervision were of a quality comparable to those found in
industrialized countries.
Chile’s central bank was well aware of the difficulty of controlling inflation and precisely
hitting the target when inflation was in the double digits, and it dealt with this problem in several
ways. First, like the industrialized countries that have adopted inflation targeting (see Bernanke,
et. al, 1999), Chile phased in inflation targeting gradually after initial successes in lowering
inflation. When the inflation objective was first announced in September 1990, it was interpreted
more as official inflation projections rather than as formal or “hard” targets. Only after the central
bank experienced success in both meeting the inflation objectives and lowering inflation, did it
begin to emphasize that the inflation objectives should be interpreted as hard targets for which the
central bank would be accountable (Felipe Morande and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, 1997). Second,
Chile’s central bank pursued a very gradualist approach to lowering its inflation objectives,.8
starting with targets of over 20% for 1991 and lowering them slowly to 3.5% by the end of the
decade. Third, because of the difficulty of controlling inflation at inflation rates which were still
above 10%, a realistic range for the inflation outcomes would have been very large. Thus, as part
of the process of hardening the inflation targets, the Chile’s central bank switched from target
ranges to point targets with its announcement in September 1994 for the 1995 objective.
The Chilean experience with inflation targeting looks quite successful. Inflation
fell from levels above 20%, when inflation projections were first introduced, to a level around
3% at present. Over the same period, output growth was very high, averaging more than 8%
per year from 1991 to 1997, a level comparable to those exhibited by the (former) Asian tigers.
Only in the last two years has the economy entered a recession with output growth falling to
3.4% in 1998 and to a -2.9% rate for the first half of 1999. In 1998 the Chilean central bank
was reluctant to ease monetary policy and let the exchange rate depreciate in order to cushion
the effects of a large, negative terms of trade shock. Instead, the Chilean central bank raised
interest rates and even narrowed the exchange rate band. In hindsight, these decisions appear
to have been a mistake: the inflation target was undershot and the economy entered a recession
for the first time in more than 15 years. Not surprisingly, the central bank came under increased
criticism and in 1999 reversed course, by lowering interest rates and allowing the peso to
depreciate.
The Chilean example suggests that inflation targeting can be used as a successful
strategy for gradual disinflation in emerging market countries, even when initial inflation is on
the order of 20%. It is important to emphasize that the success of inflation targeting cannot be
solely attributed to the actions of the Chilean central bank: supportive policies such as absence
of large fiscal deficits and rigorous regulation and supervision of the financial sector have been.9
crucial to its success.3 Another important element of Chile’s strategy has been a gradual
hardening of the targets over time. However, the experience in Chile of the last two years, as
well as that of industrialized countries, indicates that a key requirement for successful
inflation-targeting regimes in emerging market economies is the recognition that undershooting
inflation targets is just as costly as overshooting the targets. Support for an independent central
bank which is pursuing price stability can erode if the central bank is perceived as focusing
solely on lowering inflation to the detriment of other objectives such as minimizing output
variability.
In addition, Chile has not yet fully accomplished a full-fledged, inflation targeting
regime. The Chilean central bank has not yet produced an Inflation Report- type of document,
nor does it publish inflation forecasts; the accountability mechanisms of monetary policy are
also weak. Brazil, on the other hand, which adopted inflation targeting in the wake of its
currency crisis in early 1999, shows that a full-fledged inflation targeting regime can be put
in place remarkably quickly. Within four months of the announcement by the newly appointed
central bank president that inflation targeting would be adopted, the central bank of Brazil
implemented an inflation targeting regime with all the “bells and whistles” found in inflation targeters in industrialized countries, including an Inflation Report with published inflation forecasts. Despite the initial success of Brazilian inflation targeting which has kept inflation below 10% despite a substantial exchange-rate depreciation, there are still serious doubts about
whether it will be ultimately successful because it is by no means clear whether Brazil can solve its deep-rooted fiscal problems.
As noted, a critical issue for inflation targeting in emerging market countries is the role.10 of the exchange rate. Emerging market countries, including those engaging in inflation targeting, have rightfully been reluctant to adopt an attitude of “benign neglect” of exchange rate movements partly because of the existence of a sizable stock of foreign currency and/or a high degree of (partial) dollarization. Nonetheless, emerging market countries probably have
gone too far for too long in the direction of limiting exchange rate flexibility--not only through the explicit use of exchange rate bands, but also through frequent intervention in the foreign
exchange market. Responding too heavily and too frequently to movements in a “flexible”
exchange rate runs the risk of transforming the exchange rate into a nominal anchor for
monetary policy that takes precedence over the inflation target, at least in the eyes of the public.
One possible way to avoid this problem is for inflation-targeting central banks in emerging
market countries to adopt a transparent policy of smoothing short-run exchange-rate
fluctuations that helps mitigate potentially destabilizing effects of abrupt exchange rate changes
while making it clear to the public that they will allow exchange rates to reach their market-determined
level over longer horizons..11
Bernanke, Ben S.; Laubach, Thomas; Mishkin, Frederic S. and Posen, Adam S. Inflation
Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 1999.
Calvo, Guillermo. “Capital Markets and the Exchange Rate,” mimeo, University of
Maryland, October, 1999.
Edwards, Sebastian. “How Effective are Capital Controls? ” Journal of Economic Perspectives,
Fall 1999, Volume 13, #4, pp. 65-84.
Masson, Paul R., Savastano, Miguel A. and Sharma, Sunil. “The Scope for Inflation Targeting in
Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper 97/130, October, 1997.
Mishkin, Frederic S. "Understanding Financial Crises: A Developing Country Perspective,"
in Michael Bruno and Boris Pleskovic, eds., Annual World Bank Conference on
Development Economics 1996. Washington D.C.: World Bank, 1996, pp. 29-62.
Mishkin, Frederic S. “International Experiences with Different Monetary Regimes,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, 43, 1999, pp. 579-606.
Mishkin, Frederic S. and Savastano, Miguel, A. “Monetary Policy Strategies for Latin America,”
mimeo., November, 1999.
Mishkin, Frederic S. and Posen, Adam S. “Inflation Targeting: Lessons from Four Countries,”
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, August 1997: 9-110.
Morande, Felipe and Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus. “Inflation Targets and Indexation in Chile,”
mimeo, Central Bank of Chile, August, 1997..12
1. See Mishkin and Savastano (1999) for a more detailed discussion of the experience with
inflation targeting in Latin America.
2. The legislation also stipulated a central bank objective to ensure equilibria in domestic and
external payments. Partly because of this, Chile maintained an exchange rate band around a
crawling peg during most of the 1990s. Importantly, however, the central bank made it clear that
when there was a potential conflict between the exchange rate band and the inflation target, the
inflation target would take precedence.
3. The Chilean controls on short-term capital flows have often been cited as another
important factor behind the relative stability of the Chilean economy and the success of
monetary policy, but rigorous prudential supervision was probably more important. For a
recent overview of the debate surrounding Chile’s capital controls, see Sebastian Edwards,
1999.
Cele mai ok referate! www.referateok.ro |